The Social Security Trust Fund Is Not a “Get Out of Jail Free Card”

UPDATED BELOW

David Friedman, drawing on an op-ed by Thomas Saving, suggests that

Obama may have a $2.7 trillion dollar get out of jail free card, a way of spending that much additional money without exceeding the debt limit.

How does that work? Friedman explains:

Suppose no agreement is reached on raising the debt limit. Obama instructs the relevant people to spend the income from Social Security on the war in Afghanistan, bailouts, whatever he thinks needs money. He then instructs the Social Security system to cash in as many bonds as are required to meet its obligations to Social Security recipients, say $700 billion. He then instructs the treasury, since the national debt is now $700 billion below the debt limit, to borrow $700 billion. The net effect is that he has increased total expenditure, Social Security included, by $700 billion without exceeding the debt limit. The trust fund is currently at about $2.7 trillion, so he can do it for four more years.

Friedman’s scheme would work only if total federal receipts (including Social Security taxes) remain greater than or equal to total federal outlays (including SS benefits), from the point at which federal indebtedness hits the statutory ceiling. But that is not the situation.

Let us say, for the sake of argument, that the ceiling will be reached at the end of FY 2011. The president’s budget for FY 2012 shows total outlays of $3.729 trillion (including SS benefits of $0.761 T) and total revenues of $2.626 T (including SS taxes of $0.660 T). (See tables S-1 and S-3, here.) In other words, if Congress passes the president’s budget exactly as it stands, the debt ceiling must rise by $1.103 T ($3.729 T – $2.626 T) in FY 2012. And the SS trust fund, no matter how large it is, cannot alter the arithmetic.

Here is why. Suppose the feds spend all $0.660 T in SS taxes on things other than SS benefits (as they will, in effect). From an accounting standpoint, that reduces the non-SS deficit for FY 2012 from $1.001 T (non-SS spending less non-SS receipts) to $0.341 T. But the folks at SS are faced with a bill for $0.761 T in SS benefits. To pay the bill without having received a dime in SS taxes, the SS folks must go to the SS trust fund and grab U.S. treasury bonds with a value of $0.761 T, which they must then present to Tim Geithner for payment. Geithner thinks, “Who are these fools? Do they imagine that I’ve got that much unencumbered cash lying around, when I’m over my head in debt and sinking fast?” But being a good Obamanite, Geithner gives the SS folks their $0.761 T, and they go away happy.

If the analysis stops there, Friedman is correct. The treasury has just redeemed $0.761 T in bonds held by the SS trust fund, and the total debt of the federal government has magically dropped by $0.761 T. But the analysis cannot stop there, because the treasury does not have the $0.761 T in unencumbered cash. It must now borrow $0.761 T, to cover the redemption of the SS trust fund bonds, plus another $0.341 T, to cover the amount by which non-SS outlays exceed total receipts (including the SS taxes that it intercepts). With rounding, that comes to $1.103 T, which just happens to be the amount by which total federal outlays exceed total federal receipts.

Under what conditions would Friedman’s fix work? Here is a list (perhaps not an exhaustive one):

  • The debt ceiling will not be reached, given current projections of federal outlays and receipts (including SS benefits and taxes).
  • The debt ceiling has been reached but will not be exceeded, given current projections of federal outlays and receipts (including SS benefits and taxes).
  • The debt ceiling has been reached, but the surplus from non-SS programs will offset the deficit in SS accounts, or vice versa.

What about the SS trust fund? As long as the federal government is in debt by at least the face value of the SS trust fund, the trust fund has no real value. There is one (unlikely) saving condition, which is that the government’s net worth — represented by real assets — is equal to or greater than the face value of the trust fund. Such assets would have to be authorized for sale, by law, and would have to be valued at their quick-sale price on the open market. Given the reluctance with which Congress and federal agencies part with valuable assets (mainly land), it will be a cold day on the Equator before the SS trust fund is more than a valueless collection of accounting entries.

UPDATE (07/25/11)

The crux of my objection to Friedman’s scheme is found in the original post and my reply to his first comment; viz.:

If the analysis stops there, Friedman is correct. The treasury has just redeemed $0.761 T in bonds held by the SS trust fund, and the total debt of the federal government has magically dropped by $0.761 T. But the analysis cannot stop there, because the treasury does not have the $0.761 T in unencumbered cash….

*     *     *

3. This intra-governmental transaction does not affect the revenues that SS and non-SS receive from third parties.

4. Total spending by SS and non-SS must therefore equal their total receipts from third parties.

I ended my reply with this observation:

If you disagree with this analysis, then you and/or I must be making some assumptions (perhaps inadvertently) that remain hidden from view….

As it turns out, Friedman was making a hidden assumption that allows his scheme to work. That hidden assumption is revealed in a note appended to Friedman’s original post. The note was not there when I published this post, and I was unaware of it when I replied to Friedman’s first comment. In fact, I was unaware of it until late yesterday, when I revisited this post and Friedman’s after receiving his second comment. The note reads:

Some readers seem puzzled as to where the Treasury, in my story, is to find the $700 billion that it is to pay to the Social Security Administration, once the debt limit is reached. The answer is straightforward. With or without a debt limit, the federal government is continually collecting money and spending it. In my scenario, the government takes (say) $50 billion that it was supposed to pay as salary to federal employees, pays it to SSA instead. SSA cancels $50 billion in trust fund bonds. The national debt, which includes the debt owed by the federal government to the SSA, is now $50 billion below the limit, so the Treasury borrows $50 billion and pays out salaries to federal employees. Rinse and repeat as many times as necessary.

This is too clever by half. It requires exquisite timing on the part of the Treasury; otherwise, payrolls are not met, vendors are not paid, and existing debt is not serviced. In other words, the federal government would be in constructive default and violation of the debt limit. Moreover, it most certainly would not allow the federal government’s outlays to exceed its revenues over an extended period, which is why Obama seeks a higher debt limit in the first place. I could stop there, but there’s more to say about the scheme.

It resembles check-kiting, and may be just as illegal. But even if it is not illegal, it amounts to a patent evasion of the debt limit, and the evasion soon would be obvious to knowledgeable observers. Among other things, financial markets probably would react as if the federal government were in default — because the scheme could sooner or later result in a default of some kind (especially if outlays are rising as revenues stay flat). It would not take an act of Congress (over Obama’s veto) to put an end to the scheme; financial markets would do the job, as Treasury would be unable to refinance existing debt, except (possibly) at exorbitant interest rates.

In the best case, climbing interest payments would eat up revenues and force the federal government to cut back on the actual operations and programs. The result would be exactly opposite the one desired by Obama and company, which is real expansion of government. In the worst case, the Federal Reserve would pick up the tab, if it could scrape together a voting majority with the stomach for wading into a political firestorm. But that is another deus ex machina — of dubious durability — and not a surefire way of getting around the debt limit.

I am through with this subject. Comments are closed.

UPDATE (06/08/14)

I note, very belatedly, that Friedman later amended his post to add this:

A friend who knows much more law than I do writes:

It turns on, on further research, that Congress anticipated and prevented the very trick you have devised. Public Law 104-121, section 107(a), prohibits redemption of Social Security trust fund securities prior to maturity for any purpose other than the payment of benefits or administrative expenses.So it’s still true that the debt limit cannot block social security payments, at least until the trust fund runs out. But my multi-trillion dollar get out of jail free card has been cancelled.

Curses, foiled again.

Friedman later wrote a post that is properly focused on the ability of the federal government to continue paying SS benefits, regardless of the debt ceiling, as long as the trust fund is sufficiently large. The trustees expect the fund to be exhausted in 2033.

4 thoughts on “The Social Security Trust Fund Is Not a “Get Out of Jail Free Card”

  1. I am afraid I do not see what you think the (legal) problem is. As I point out in the part of my piece you do not mention, the Treasury could in principle instruct the SSA to cash in bonds beyond what are needed to pay Social Security checks and hand the money over to Treasury for other purposes. The national debt drops by the amount of bonds cashed in, since the trust fund, which has now gone down, is part of the debt, so the Treasury can then borrow the same amount without exceeding the debt limit. It has now, in effect, borrowed the additional money it needed while still respecting the limit.

    You write that the trust fund cannot alter the arithmetic, but never explain why. In the simple version of my proposal, where all SS revenue goes to general expenditure, cashing in trust fund bonds for (say) $800 billion of SS payments means that total government expenditure, SS included, is $800 higher than it otherwise would have been, even though it is still consistent with the debt limit. Is that not a change in the arithmetic?

    Nor do I see where, in your version, Geithner’s problem paying the SSA comes from. Even if the U.S. is at the debt limit, it is receiving and paying out large amounts of money every day. So Geithner takes $10 billion that was supposed to go to pay salaries of government employees and pays it to SSA instead. Doing so reduces the debt by $10 billion, so he is now that far below the limit, so he borrows $10 billion to pay salaries. Rinse and repeat as many times as necessary.

    It sounds as though you did not follow the argument, but perhaps I am misunderstanding you and you can clarify.

    Like

  2. You say, quite clearly, that the federal government can spend $700 B more than it takes in, simply by redeeming SS trust-fund bonds in the amount of $700 B. I must disagree.

    The problem isn’t legal, it’s a matter of accounting and cash flow. I admit that my exposition is convoluted, so I’ll try to keep it simple.

    I’ll begin with a homely example:

    Let’s say that my wife and I have a combined indebtedness of zero, and we want to keep it that way. Let’s say, also, that I have borrowed $1000 from my wife. On our joint balance sheet, she has an asset of $1,000 (the loan to me) and I have a liability of $1,000 (the debt to her); these items cancel on our joint balance sheet, so our combined indebtedness is zero. And as long as our combined income equals our combined expenses, our combined indebtedness will remain zero.

    Now, if my wife calls in my debt, and I give her $1,000, our combined indebtedness remains zero — as long as our combined income continues to equal our combined expenses. But for that to happen, I must reduce my expenses by $1,000 in order to pay off the loan from her. She can then use the $1000 to increase her expenses by $1000, but our combined expenses cannot increase.

    Let’s translate this to the federal government, which (for the present purpose) has two components, SS and non-SS;

    SS has an asset in the form of debt issued by non-SS; that debt was incurred when non-SS took some of SS’s income and spent it. On the federal balance sheet, SS’s asset is canceled by non-SS’s debt. The net amount of federal debt is whatever non-SS owes to third parties. The federal government then imposes on itself a rule that the net amount of debt cannot increase beyond its current level.

    How, then, can the federal government spend more than it receives in revenues without breaking its rule against increasing its debt? Let’s spell it out:

    1. SS calls in $700 B in debt owed by non-SS.

    2. Non-SS pays the $700 B to SS, thus eliminating the intra-governmental debt but not changing the net indebtedness of the federal government, which remains the same.

    3. This intra-governmental transaction does not affect the revenues that SS and non-SS receive from third parties.

    4. Total spending by SS and non-SS must therefore equal their total receipts from third parties.

    5. Any additional spending by SS must be offset by spending cuts on the part of non-SS, and vice versa.

    If you disagree with this analysis, then you and/or I must be making some assumptions (perhaps inadvertently) that remain hidden from view. Let me know what you think.

    Like

  3. “If you disagree with this analysis, then you and/or I must be making some assumptions (perhaps inadvertently) that remain hidden from view. ”

    Yes. You are assuming that total indebtedness can’t change. But obviously it can–that, after all, is the point of the attempt to raise the debt limit. I am describing a way in which the total indebtedness of the federal government, SSA included, increases, but the national debt as currently measured does not–because the national debt includes debt owed by the federal government to the SSA.

    You write: “Non-SS pays the $700 B to SS, thus eliminating the intra-governmental debt but not changing the net indebtedness of the federal government, which remains the same.”

    The net indebtedness is not what the debt limit is on, as I have tried to explain. The limit is on the indebtedness of the federal government, which includes what it owes the SSA as a liability, does not include what is owed by it to the SSA as an asset.

    Like

Comments are closed.